INNOVATIVE FINANCING
FOR DEVELOPMENT:
Scalable Business Models that
Produce Economic, Social, and
Environmental Outcomes
September 2014
Innovative Financing Initiative
An initiative of the Global
Development Incubator
www.globaldevincubator.org
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
This study builds on the existing knowledge and research
of many financing and development experts from the public
and private sectors. The findings and analysis in the pages
that follow would not have been possible without the indi-
viduals from more than 50 organizations who shared data,
insights, and perspectives.
The authors would like to acknowledge and thank the
sponsors of this work—the Citi Foundation and the Agence
Française de Développement (AFD)—for their support
and financing.
The authors would also like to thank the members of the
project’s advisory committee. Specifically, we would like to
acknowledge Graham Macmillan and Hui Wen Chan from
Citi Foundation, Agnès Biscaglia from AFD, Andrew Stern
and Alice Gugelev from the Global Development Incubator,
and Henrik Skovby from Dalberg Group. Their generous
contribution of time, direction, and energy has been vital to
the success of this research.
This study was authored by Dr. Serena Guarnaschelli, Sam
Lampert, Ellie Marsh, and Lucy Johnson of Dalberg Global
Development Advisors, in collaboration with Sara Wallace,
who provided editorial expertise.
This is an independently drafted report and so all views ex-
pressed are those of Dalberg Global Development Advisors
and do not necessarily represent the views of the report’s
sponsors. Although the authors have made every effort to
ensure that the information in this report was correct at
time of print, Dalberg Global Development Advisors does
not assume and hereby disclaims any liability for the accu-
racy of the data, or any consequence of its use.
i
TABLE OF CONTENTS
Executive Summary ............................................................................................................................................................. iii
Introduction: The Unrealized Potential Of Innovative Financing ....................................................................................... v
Chapter 1: What Is Innovative Financing? ........................................................................................................................... 1
Definition .............................................................................................................................................................................. 1
Market Overview ................................................................................................................................................................. 3
Trends And Evolutions Of Innovative Financing Mechanisms ............................................................................................. 7
Chapter 2: How Does Innovative Financing Create Value? ...............................................................................................10
Outcomes For Consumers And Private Companies ............................................................................................................10
Outcomes For National Governments ............................................................................................................................... 12
Outcomes For International Donors ................................................................................................................................... 18
Chapter 3: What Are The Next Steps For Innovative Financing? ..................................................................................... 20
Opportunities ..................................................................................................................................................................... 20
Constraints ......................................................................................................................................................................... 21
Proposed Solutions And Roles For Different Actors ........................................................................................................... 23
Conclusion ......................................................................................................................................................................... 25
Annex 1: Methodology And Definitions ............................................................................................................................ 26
Annex 2: Selected References ........................................................................................................................................... 30
Innovative Financing for Development: Scalable Business Models that Produce Economic, Social, and Environmental Outcomesii
Figure 1: A successful transition to sustainable development will require substantial resources ......................................... vi
Figure 2: Innovative financing is a small component of public assistance............................................................................. vii
Figure 3: Innovative financing instruments introduce new products, expand into new markets, and attract
new participants ........................................................................................................................................................ 2
Figure 4: Bonds and guarantees are the largest innovative financing mechanisms ................................................................ 4
Figure 5: Innovative financing mechanisms have focused on a range of development challenges ......................................... 5
Figure 6: Most innovative financing mechanisms support transfers between the public and private sectors ........................ 6
Figure 7: The majority of instruments target risk-adjusted market returns .............................................................................. 6
Figure 8: Innovative financing has grown through the introduction of new instruments ........................................................ 7
Figure 9: Innovative financing increasingly targets market returns ......................................................................................... 8
Figure 10: Established instruments rely on standards and mobilize more resources .............................................................. 8
Figure 11: Innovative financing instruments produce a range of outcomes ...........................................................................11
Figure 12: The market for green bonds is growing ................................................................................................................ 13
Figure 13: Impact investing focuses on social sectors .......................................................................................................... 15
Figure 14: MIGA exposure has shifted to Sub-Saharan Africa ............................................................................................... 16
Figure 15: Political risk is perceived as a barrier to investment and demand for investment insurance is growing ............... 17
Figure 16: Long-term political risk insurance is becoming more widely available .................................................................. 17
Figure 17: Illustrative cash flows of a Development Impact Bond ......................................................................................... 19
Figure 18: The focus of innovative financing is changing ....................................................................................................... 21
Figure 19: Innovative financing mechanisms are projected to mobilize $24 billion per year by 2020 based
on historical performance ...................................................................................................................................... 22
LIST OF FIGURES
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY iii
Innovative financing is the manifestation of two impor-
tant trends in international development: an increased
focus on programs that deliver results and a desire to
support collaboration between the public and private
sector. Innovative financing instruments complement
traditional international resource flows—such as aid, foreign
direct investment, and remittances—to mobilize additional
resources for development and address specific market
failures and institutional barriers. Innovative financing is
an essential tool as the development community strives
to eliminate poverty, raise living standards, and protect
the environment.
This report aims to accelerate the growth of innovative
finance by creating a common language and vision for
leaders in both the public and private sector to use as
they explore innovative financing opportunities. Thus
far, a lack of clarity about what innovative financing is and
how standards can help compare the performance of dif-
ferent mechanisms has inhibited broader participation in
the sector and increased transaction costs associated with
the creation of new products. We believe that this report
can help by creating a common understanding of innova-
tive financing, providing an overview of the market, and
identifying opportunities for public and private sector actors
to make innovative financing commitments.
Innovative finance is not financial innovation. It encom-
passes a broad range of financial instruments and assets
including securities and derivatives, results-based financing,
and voluntary or compulsory contributions—all of which
this report explores in more detail. Established financial
instruments, such as guarantees and bonds, constitute
nearly 65% of the innovative financing market; while new
products dominate many conversations about innovative
financing, most resources mobilized through innovative
financing use existing products in new markets, or involve
new investors. Our definition of the “innovation” aspect of
innovative financing includes the introduction of new prod-
ucts, the extension of existing products to new markets,
and the presence of new types of investors.
Within this broad definition, innovative financing
has mobilized nearly $100 billion and grown by ap-
proximately 11% per year between 2001 and 2013. This
growth reflects the emergence of results-based financing
as an important tool for achieving development outcomes
and the capability of instruments such as bonds and invest-
ment funds to provide risk-adjusted returns for private
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
Innovative Financing for Development: Scalable Business Models that Produce Economic, Social, and Environmental Outcomesiv
investors. Innovative financing instruments are emerging in
a variety of additional development areas—a few examples
include low-carbon infrastructure, mechanisms to improve
access to finance, and tools to reduce the cost of life-sav-
ing commodities.
Successful innovative financing instruments address
a specific market failure, catalyze political momentum
to increase and coordinate the resources of multiple
governments, and offer contractual certainty to inves-
tors. Often, innovative financing instruments reallocate
risks from investors to institutions better positioned to
bear the risk and, in the process, enable participation from
mainstream investors. Instruments that have mobilized
significant resources benefit from relatively simple financial
structures and a proven track record that clearly describes
the financial and social returns for investors.
The focus of innovative financing is shifting from the
mobilization of resources through innovative fundrais-
ing approaches to the delivery of positive social and
environmental outcomes through market-based instru-
ments. We anticipate three primary drivers of growth in the
innovative financing sector:
• Increased use of established financial instruments.
Established instruments that investors can evaluate
through existing risk frameworks, such as green bonds,
will attract new participants including pension funds
and institutional investors. Channeling the proceeds of
these instruments to productive development goals will
require new standards that specify how funds can be
used most effectively.
• Expansion into new markets through growth of repli-
cable products. Over the past ten years, the interna-
tional development community has experimented with
new instruments such as performance-based contracts.
These instruments do not yet have the track record
to attract institutional investors, but offer promising
opportunities to improve development outcomes in
new sectors.
• Creation of new innovative financing products. Finally,
we have seen the emergence of new products that are
theoretically promising, but have not yet demonstrated
results. While these products will remain a small portion
of the market in the short-term, we encourage donor
governments and other funders to continue experiment-
ing with these products so they can mature into the
next important asset class.
This report is the cornerstone of the Innovative Financing
Initiative, a coordinated effort led by public and private
institutions to facilitate more efficient markets by providing
performance data on past investments, catalyzing invest-
ments through engagement with new actors, and develop-
ing and promoting new products through work with leading
international development organizations. Building on past
efforts to describe innovative finance schemes, we identify
common characteristics of different initiatives, assess the
market demand for new models, and propose mechanisms
that can unlock the sectors potential. These proposed
mechanisms include an innovative financing exchange to
provide performance data and technical assistance, a mar-
keting facility to expand the reach of established products,
and an incubator to reduce the costs associated with creat-
ing new instruments.
The future we want—a future that meets the needs of
people and the planet—will require an estimated trillions of
dollars in investment over the next ten years. We will need
to harness all possible sources of financing to address
global economic, social, and environmental challenges.
We hope to explore existing questions and promote new
solutions with our partners, expert advisors, and other par-
ticipants. If you are interested in joining the conversation,
please contact us at innovativefinance@dalberg.com. We
look forward to talking with you.
INTRODUCTION: The Unrealized Potential Of Innovative Financing v
INTRODUCTION:
The Unrealized Potential of Innovative Financing
The public sector will require trillions of dollars in capi-
tal and significant expertise from the private sector to
meet development objectives. The initial investments and
ongoing costs needed to eradicate poverty, provide public
goods (such as health and education), and manage the
natural resource base for economic and social development
will cost an estimated one trillion dollars per year or more.
1
Mitigating the effects of climate change and adapting to
new climate realities will also require hundreds of billions
of dollars. Resources required to achieve milestones set
out by development agendas, including the Millennium
Development Goals (MDGs) and their post-2015 successor,
the Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs), will be lower
than costs associated with adapting to and mitigating the
effects of climate change, but will still likely exceed $100
billion per year. The public sector does not have the resourc-
es to support all of these needs alone.
Governments, international institutions, and private
actors recognize the magnitude of this challenge. They
have begun to understand the limitations of existing ap-
proaches to international assistance and have made efforts
1 These estimates are based on the literature review found in “Financing
for sustainable development: Review of global investment requirement
estimates”, UNTT Working Group on Sustainable Development
Financing, 2013.
to improve aid effectiveness and engage the private sector
through agreements such as the 2005 Paris Declaration
on Aid Effectiveness, the 2008 Accra Agenda for Action,
and the 2011 Busan Partnership for Effective Development
Cooperation. Likewise, many private sector actors have
made public commitments to promoting sustainability
in their activities. For example, the 1260 signatories of
the United Nations-supported Principles for Responsible
Investment Initiative—including asset owners, investment
managers, and service providers—have $45 trillion dollars
in assets under management.
2
This commitment and oth-
ers reflect a growing recognition by the private sector of
the rewards of promoting economic and social prosperity
and environmental sustainability through their operations.
Innovative financing is critical to creating opportunities
for public-private sector collaboration that will help ad-
dress global challenges. Innovative financing has several
benefits compared to traditional financial approaches. For
example, it:
• Deploys significant, new private sector capital that
would otherwise not participate in social investments.
While not all of innovative financing capital is additional
2 See http://www.unpri.org/about-pri/about-pri/ for more information
(accessed September 2014).
Innovative Financing for Development: Scalable Business Models that Produce Economic, Social, and Environmental Outcomesvi
Figure 1: A successful transition to sustainable development will require substantial resources
10 100 1,000 10,000
MDGs/SDGs
Infrastructure (non energy)
Land and Agriculture
Energy Efficiency
Renewable Energy
Universal Access to Energy
Climate Change Adaptation
Climate Change Mitigation
Biodiversity
Forests
Oceans
Estimates of annual investment needs for selected sustainable development sectors
USD billions
Notes: The x-axis is in logarithmic scale. There is significant overlap across sectors. MDGs/SDGs stand for the Millennium Development Goals and their post-2015
successors, the Sustainable Development Goals.
Source: UNTT Working Group on Sustainable Development Financing, “Financing for Sustainable Development: Review of global investment requirement esti-
mates”, 2013.
Box 1: Innovative Financing has evolved from mobilizing resources to private sector engagement
Policies and conferences
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
Creation of the MDGs
Sri Lanka Development Bonds
EU ETS
Solidarity Levy on Airline Tickets
IFFIm
Product (RED)
Debt2Health
Green Bonds
AMC for Pneumococcal
Results-based financing
Financial Transaction Tax
Development Impact Bonds
Prominent Initiatives
Engaging
the
private
sector
(2006-
2015)
Aid-based
pilots
(2000-
2005)
International Conference on Financing for Development, Monterrey
Geneva & New York Declaration: Initiative to fight hunger and poverty; First global
intergovernmental dialogue on innovative means for financing development
Millennium Summit; Declaration on Innovative Sources of Financing for Development
Paris Conference on Innovative Development Financing Mechanisms:
Leading Group on Innovative Finance for Development created
International Conference for Financing for Development, Doha:
Doha Declaration on Innovative Financing for Development
I-8 Group created
General Assembly resolution devoted to innovative sources of financing for development
Busan Declaration to further develop innovative finance mechanisms to mobilize private
finance for share development goals; Rio Declaration to scale up innovative financing
UN General Assembly to develop post-2015 goals
Source: World Economic Social Survey 2012 “In Search of New Development Finance, Department of Economic and Social Affairs UN; “Delivering the Post-2015
Development Agenda: Options for a New Global Partnership”, Center on International Cooperation 2013; Dalberg analysis.
INTRODUCTION: The Unrealized Potential Of Innovative Financing vii
to either government official direct assistance (ODA) or
private philanthropic contributions, successful mecha-
nisms often channel resources to projects that would
not otherwise receive them. For example, guarantees
that enable investments in public goods (such as infra-
structure) and impact investing funds support small and
medium enterprises that might otherwise struggle to
access capital.
• Transforms financial assets through financial structuring
and intermediation to meet the needs of development
programs by distributing risk, enhancing liquidity, reduc-
ing volatility, and avoiding timing mismatches. Innovative
financing mechanisms channel funds from people and
institutions that want to make investments, to projects
that require more resources than traditional donors and
philanthropies can provide. For example, green bonds
and other thematic bonds provide capital to support
investments in low-carbon infrastructure such as wind
farms, sustainable forestry management, and urban
infrastructure. In addition, innovative financing mecha-
nisms such as the Pledge Guarantee for Health provide
bridge financing for projects and institutions during the
gap period between when resources are committed and
resources are disbursed.
• Supports a cooperative public-private sector approach
to scale socially beneficial operations that require
significant capital outlays and traditionally sit squarely in
the realm of the public sector. In many sectors—such as
health, financial services, and agriculture—private com-
panies with the expertise to design, produce, market,
and distribute new products are crucial to creating social
change. Innovative financing mechanisms can adjust
incentives to encourage private companies to make
the investments necessary to create new products
and enter new markets. For example, the pneumococ-
cal advance market commitment sponsored by GAVI
reallocated demand risk for pneumococcal vaccines
in developing countries, which allowed pharmaceuti-
cal companies to produce more vaccines at scale and
dramatically lower the vaccines’ cost per dose.
Private sector actors have also benefited from innova-
tive financing mechanisms. In addition to creating chan-
nels for private actors to deploy capital to support develop-
ment, innovative financing mechanisms also offer private
sector actors risk-adjusted financial returns and access to
new markets. Bonds guaranteed by AAA rated international
organizations and issued in currencies with low volatility
offer a low-risk opportunity for both institutional and retail
investors to buy low-risk assets while channelling resources
to sectors that support positive development outcomes.
Most microfinance investment funds and impact invest-
ing funds also aim to offer risk-adjusted market returns.
Figure 2: Innovative financing is a small component of public assistance
Evolution of funding for public goods in developing countries, 2001-2012
$ billions
1,000
150
300
0
250
200
100
50
0
4,000
4,500
6,000
3,000
3,500
2,000
2,500
1,500
500
5,000
5,500
72
200
4
200
5
3
13
61
5
200
9
2
96
9
77
110
137
200
8
2010
75
69
143
9
99
132
2011
59
148
200
6
200
3
Official aid flows and innovative financing resources mobilized
152
114
4
3
2012
Net Total Developing Country Government Expenditure
11
107
9
200
7
147
131
8
140
123
200
2
135
100
200
1
3
54
51
Innovative financing resources mobilized (left axis)
Official aid flows (left axis)
Net government expenditure (right axis)
Notes: Net Government expenditure does not include general budget support and loan disbursement to public sector; Official aid flows include Official
Development Assistance and Others Official Flows; Innovative finance data is based on 278 innovative finance initiatives where volume data broken down by year
was available. It assumes that innovative financing is additional to official aid.
Source: Development initiatives, “Investments to End Poverty,” 2013; OECD DAC Table 1; Innovative Financing Initiative Database; Dalberg analysis.
Innovative Financing for Development: Scalable Business Models that Produce Economic, Social, and Environmental Outcomesviii
Guarantees can facilitate investments in new markets,
while results-based financing and performance-based con-
tracts create opportunities for private companies to profit-
ably provide goods and services in markets they otherwise
would not touch.
Despite its benefits, innovative financing remains a
small component of public sector development as-
sistance. While the public sector has expressed renewed
interest in engaging the private sector, few successful
partnerships have been formed. Innovative financing is a
small component of ODA, and an even smaller percentage
of government expenditures in developing countries and
foreign direct investment.
Innovative financing is hampered by an inefficient mar-
ket that constrains supply and diminishes demand. The
cost of developing and deploying new mechanisms, the
limited participation of investors beyond the traditional aid
community, and the lack of effective feedback loops have
thus far prevented innovative financing from reaching its
potential. If the sector can recognize and surmount these
barriers, it will be able to grow and create opportunities for
bankable investments to drive new solutions to develop-
ment challenges.
Within the development community, there is a clear
need—and a professed desire—to collaborate on in-
novative financing. This report asks: how can private
and public sector funders collaborate to channel more
resources to achieve development outcomes? Beyond
focusing on innovative financing as a source of capital that
complements traditional assistance, the report focuses on
how specific innovative financing mechanisms can support
development goals. The report is the cornerstone of a larger
initiative that mobilizes investors, companies, and policy-
makers to use innovative financing approaches to achieve
development goals.
A common language that appeals to actors in both
the private and public sector will facilitate the growth
of innovative financing. Through over 100 discussions
with representatives of government agencies, banks,
foundations, non-profits, and private companies, we have
heard concerns that innovative financing advocates fail to
understand the business models of private investors, fears
that private companies will earn extraordinary profits at the
expense of the world’s poor, and disappointment at the
lack of transparency and performance history within the
market. This report, which was co-sponsored by a corporate
foundation and a donor government, aims to address these
issues directly by highlighting how novel instruments and
initiatives can produce positive outcomes for both public
and private actors.
This report intends to demonstrate how innovative
financing can align with the strategic objectives of mul-
tinational corporations, financial institutions, interna-
tional development agencies, and private foundations—
and enable collaboration among these groups.
It is our hope that after reading this report:
• Multinational corporations and financial institutions
will understand opportunities for investment and col-
laboration that support their business models and align
with shareholder expectations.
• International development agencies will recognize the
potential for innovative financing mechanisms to sup-
port engagement with the private sector and address
specific global challenges.
• Private foundations will identify ways to engage with
public and private institutions to mobilize resources,
share information, and make strategic investments in
novel ideas.
CHAPTER 1: What is Innovative Financing? 1
Definition
Innovative financing means different things to different
people. In our interviews, we heard two distinct dimen-
sions of innovative financing. The first focuses on innovative
financing as a source of capital that complements existing
flows, particularly those from governments and philan-
thropies. Within this vision, innovative financing provides
resources that are stable, predictable, and supplemental to
official development assistance (ODA) from donor coun-
tries. The second dimension focuses on innovative financing
as a deployment (or use) of capital. This dimension focuses
on ways that innovative financing mechanisms can make
development initiatives more effective and efficient by
redistributing risk, increasing liquidity, and matching the
duration of investments with project needs. Our definition
of innovative financing mechanisms for development (“in-
novative financing”) encompasses both visions: approaches
to mobilize resources and to increase the effectiveness and
efficiency of financial flows that address global social and
environmental challenges.
The innovative financing landscape is showing a shift
from basic resource mobilization tools to a diverse
range of solutions-driven financing instruments. In
2001, bonds and guarantees focused primarily on resource
mobilization by leveraging the balance sheets of internation-
al finance institutions. Instead of providing funding at the
present time, public institutions either promised to repay
loans in the future or accepted the risk that projects may
not succeed, in order to encourage commercial investment.
In recent years, however, instruments through which the
private sector shares the risks and rewards from develop-
ment have gained more traction. This balance can occur
through an equity stake—which we often see in microfi-
nance and investment funds—or through results-based
financing mechanisms such as performance based con-
tracts or awards and prizes. Within international develop-
ment, which relies extensively on grant financing, this is an
important paradigm shift.
Our description of the market considers three dimen-
sions of existing innovative financing instruments:
type of instrument, characteristics of the innovation,
and financial function. We identified 14 different types
of instruments that are frequently classified as innovative
financing. For each type instrument, we found examples of
instruments that successfully mobilized resources for a de-
veloping country, demonstrated innovation, and used finan-
cial solutions to support positive development outcomes.
Figure 3 provides an overview of what these instruments
CHAPTER 1:
What is Innovative Financing?
Innovative Financing for Development: Scalable Business Models that Produce Economic, Social, and Environmental Outcomes2
are, why we consider them innovative, and how they sup-
port international development.
Innovation is in the eye of the beholder. Innovative
financing is innovative when it deploys proven approaches
to new markets (including both new customers and new
segments), introduces novel approaches to established
problems (including new asset types), or attracts new
participants to the market (such as commercially-oriented
investors). For example, microfinance pioneers extended an
established service to a new market and, eventually, new
participants. Advance market commitments developed a
new approach to create incentives for commercial suppli-
ers to bring their products to market. Green bonds use an
established product—bonds issued by companies and in-
stitutions—to channel capital from institutional investors to
address a global challenge. Collectively, these mechanisms
represent innovative ways of achieving development goals.
Innovative financing creates value by producing posi-
tive development outcomes. In our survey of innovative
financing mechanisms, we identified three distinct chan-
nels by which innovative financing creates value: resource
mobilization, financial intermediation, and resource delivery.
While many schemes achieve two or three of these goals
simultaneously—and almost all mobilize resources—
this framework provides a high-level overview of the
main channels:
• Resource mobilization. Innovative financing brings ad-
ditional resources to bear for development challenges.
The mobilization of resources includes mandatory
mechanisms that capture the effects of negative exter-
nalities (e.g., Pigouvian taxes), voluntary mechanisms
(e.g., lotteries), and mechanisms that combine commer-
cial and philanthropic objectives (e.g., Product(Red)).
• Financial intermediation. Innovative financing creates
efficiencies by distributing risks across many parties, en-
hancing liquidity, and pooling resources. The intermedia-
tion function includes the development of institutional
capacity to reduce transaction costs (e.g., by pooling
small investment opportunities) and to reduce or share
financial and delivery risks (e.g., by promoting invest-
ment insurance).
• Resource delivery. Delivery refers to the allocation and
expenditure of resources either as part of an invest-
ment or as direct funding for development programs. It
includes initiatives that support a more effective deploy-
ment of resources by increasing the level of transpar-
ency (e.g., through commonly accepted metrics),
creating and aligning incentives (e.g., through pay-for-
performance contracts), and coordinating the activities
of different actors.
Figure 3: Innovative financing instruments introduce new products, expand into new markets, and attract new
participants
What is innovative? How does it support development?
New
Product
New Market New
Participants
Mobilize
Resources
Financial
Intermediations
Deliver
Resources
Securities and Derivatives
Bonds and Notes
X X X
Guarantees
X X X
Loans
X X
Microfinance Investment Funds
X X X
Other Investment Funds
X X X
Other Derivative Products
X X X X
Results-based Financing
Advanced market commitments
X X X
Awards and Prizes
X X
Development Impact Bonds
X X
Performance-based contracts
X X
Debt-swaps and buy-downs
X X
Voluntary contributions
Carbon Auctions (voluntary)
X X X X
Consumer Donations
X X
Compulsory charges
Taxes
X X
CHAPTER 1: What is Innovative Financing? 3
Market Overview
Using our broad definition, innovative financing
mechanisms have mobilized $94 billion since 2000. To
gain a better understanding of this market, we conducted
a survey of nearly 350 financing mechanisms that have
been recognized as innovative financing. In this survey, we
identified four distinct clusters that encompass 14 different
categories of instruments. Figure 4 provides an overview of
the categories that constitute innovative financing. In this
report, we use the term “amount mobilized” to compare
different mechanisms. Amount mobilized”—which ac-
counts for the amount disbursed directly (for example, by
an investment fund) or indirectly (for example, by a com-
pany as a result of a guarantee)—differs from “total amount
committed,” which represents the amount originally
promised by investors, or the total amount invested. For
example, in the case of guarantees, “amount mobilized”
represents the total contingent liability of the mechanisms,
and in the case of investment funds, it represents the
total assets under management. More information about
our methodology, including a definition of each instrument
category, is in Annex 1.
3
3 While our definition of innovative financing is broad, we decided to
exclude some asset classes from our survey. We did not include bonds
to fund infrastructure or public private partnerships (PPPs) that focus on
infrastructure investment. In addition, we only considered mechanisms
where resources were deployed in developing countries. For example,
the Social Impact Bonds in the UK were intentionally excluded from our
study because they mobilized resources from within the UK that were
used within the UK.
Innovative financing is not financial innovation. The two
asset classes that mobilize the most resources, bonds and
guarantees, have existed for centuries. Bonds were first
issued by city-states in renaissance Italy in the 14th century
and insurance was first provided in 2500 BC to support the
transport of goods in Babylonia.
4
Even within the context of
international development, bonds and guarantees are not
new tools. The Multilateral Investment Guarantee Agency
(MIGA) was established in 1988, for example, and the Asian
Development Bank introduced partial risk guarantees in
1995. While the use of thematic bonds is relatively recent,
the World Bank has been issuing general purpose bonds
since 1947. Other instruments, such as microfinance funds
and impact investing funds, represent new and innovative
models for providing access to finance, but their underly-
ing business models are also well established within the
financial services industry.
Securities and derivatives constitute more than 80%
of the amount mobilized between 2000 and 2013. The
largest category within securities and derivatives is guar-
antees ($36 billion, or 39% of the total), which reflects the
public sector’s ability to leverage capital by providing credit
enhancements. It also reflects the importance of MIGA,
which is the largest single mechanism in the database and
mobilized $24 billion between 2000 and 2013 (26% of the
total). Even when removing this large mechanism from the
database, securities and derivatives mobilized $53 billion
4 World Economic Forum, Rethinking Financial Innovation - Reducing
Negative Outcomes While Retaining The Benefits, 2012
Box 2: Definitions of innovative financing from leading institutions
World Bank
“Innovative financing involves non-traditional applications of
solidarity, public private partnerships, and catalytic mechanisms
that (i) support fundraising by tapping new sources and engaging
investors beyond the financial dimension of transactions, as
partners and stakeholders in development; or (ii) deliver financial
solutions to development problems on the ground.
World Bank (2009), Innovating Development Finance:
From Financing Sources to Financial Solutions.
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development
(OECD)
“Innovative financing comprises mechanisms of raising funds or
stimulating actions in support of international development that
go beyond traditional spending approaches by either the official
or private sectors, such as: 1) new approaches for pooling private
and public revenue streams to scale up or develop activities for
the benefit of partner countries; 2) new revenue streams (e.g.,
a new tax, charge, fee, bond raising, sale proceed or voluntary
contribution scheme) earmarked to developmental activities on
a multi-year basis; and 3) new incentives (financial guarantees,
corporate social responsibility or other rewards or recognition)
to address market failures or scale up ongoing developmental
activities.
—OECD (2009), Innovative Financing to Fund Development: Progress
and Prospects.
Leading Group on Innovative Financing for Development
An innovative development financing mechanism is a mecha-
nism for raising funds for development. The mechanisms are
complementary to Official Development Assistance. They are
also predictable and stable. They are closely linked to the idea of
global public goods and aimed at correcting the negative effects
of globalization.
—Leading Group on Innovative Financing
for Development (2012), FAQs: Innovative Financing
Innovative Financing for Development: Scalable Business Models that Produce Economic, Social, and Environmental Outcomes4
from 2000 to 2013 (56% of the total). After guarantees,
thematic bonds—which dedicate resources to specific
development goals such as low-carbon infrastructure—have
mobilized the most resources ($23 billion or 25% of the to-
tal). Combined, these two asset classes make up over half
of the total amount mobilized through innovative financing.
Results-based financing is the second largest category
of mechanisms. Results-based financing refers to mecha-
nisms which use incentive-based payments to increase the
performance of investments and to transfer risk from the
investor that funds the delivery of goods and services to
the company or NGO that provides the goods and services.
The mechanism is an explicit contract between the out-
come funder and the delegated implementer who receives
a payment. Most results-based financing mechanisms,
such as performance based contracts ($5 billion mobilized
or 5% of the total) and advance market commitments ($1
billion mobilized or 1% of the total) are direct contracts be-
tween the public sector and a private sector implementer.
While small, results-based financing has grown rapidly from
$4 million in 2003 to $1.3 billion in 2012 (80% per year on
average). In addition, development impact bonds (DIBs) pro-
vide a new way to pool performance-based contracts and
facilitate private investment. While DIBs did not mobilize
resources between 2000 and 2013, new opportunities are
coming to market.
5
Voluntary and compulsory contributions contribute
only 10% of the total innovative financing mechanisms.
The largest mechanism within this category is the voluntary
carbon market in which companies purchase carbon credits
to offset emissions. Other voluntary mechanisms, such as
efforts to tie a percentage of companies’ profits to global
challenges, have limited scale and are difficult to replicate.
For example, since 2001, Product(Red) has contributed
$215 million to the Global Fund—this amount represents
less than 1% of total contributions to the fund.
6
Within the
category of compulsory contributions, the largest single
example is the “solidarity levy on airline tickets,” a small tax
5 For example, D. Capital launched a DIB to support malaria prevention
and control in Mozambique in 2013. In 2014, UBS Optimus Foundation
and the Childrens Investment Fund Foundation recently approved
funding for the first DIB in education, supporting the work of Educate
Girls, an NGO operating in government-run schools in Rajasthan, to
enroll and retain girls as well as improve learning outcomes for all
children.
6 Global Fund Pledges and Contributions to Date, http://
www.theglobalfund.org/documents/core/financial/
Core_PledgesContributions_List_en
Figure 4: Bonds and guarantees are the largest innovative financing mechanisms
Amount mobilized by innovative financing mechanisms, 2000-2013
Percent of total mobilized (n=278)
Bonds ; 24.8%
Guarantees
;
38.6%
Development Impact Bonds; 0.0%
Investment funds
; 8.1%
Microfinance
; 9.8%
Other derivative products
; 0.6%
Awards and Prizes
; 0.3%
Advanced Market Commitments
; 1.2%
Debt-swaps and buydowns
- - ; 1.5%
Performance-based contracts
; 5.3%
Consumer purchases
; 0.2%
Auctions
; 6.9%
Taxes and
Levies
; 2.6%
Source: Innovative Financing Initiative Database; Dalberg analysis
Securities and Derivatives
Results-based mechanisms
Voluntary Contributions
Compulsory Charges
Source: Innovative Financing Initiative Database; Dalberg analysis.
CHAPTER 1: What is Innovative Financing? 5
Figure 5: Innovative financing mechanisms have focused on a range of development challenges
Innovative financing mechanism by sector
1.2
1.0
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0.0
Average size of mechanism (USD billion)
Number of mechanism
Access to
Finance
155
24
27
44
160
140
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
4
4
2
5
83
Energy and
Environment
Agriculture Health Disaster
Response
Education Housing Technology Multiple
Number (left axis)
Average instrument size (right axis)
E.g. microfinance, SMEs,
investment funds
E.g. guarantee facilities,
funds, currency swaps with
multi-sector mandates
Note: Sector information was available for 348 mechanisms. Average initiative size was based on data for 278 mechanisms. Other smaller sectors not shown
include Technology, Housing and Urban Development, Water and Sanitation, ICT and Media.
Source: Innovative Financing Initiative Database; Dalberg analysis.
on airline tickets in certain countries that mobilizes private
sector funds to support UNITAID.
7
It has raised $1.9 billion,
or 65% of UNITAID’s funds, since its inception in 2006.
An independent evaluation found that the levy has had no
negative effects on airline revenue or profitability, air traffic,
travel industry jobs, or tourism. While taxes and levies are
established tools for transferring resources from the private
sector to public purposes, novel mechanisms such as the
solidarity levy have successfully given international develop-
ment actors an additional and predictable revenue source.
Many innovative financing initiatives seek to effect
change in various sectors, which indicates a desire by
initiative sponsors to diversify exposure and highlights
the need for cross-cutting solutions to address financial
challenges shared by many sectors. Since 2000, innova-
tive financing mechanisms have mobilized over $30 billion
to support investments in energy and environment ($14
billion), access to finance ($9 billion), and global health ($7
billion), with an additional $43 billion across multiple sec-
tors. Innovative financing has had limited interaction with
the agriculture, education, and water sectors.
7 Nine countries have implemented the air ticket levy: Cameroon, Chile,
Congo, France, Madagascar, Mali, Mauritius, Niger and the Republic of
Korea.
Nearly all innovative financing mechanisms combine
public sector resources with private sector resources
and expertise. In terms of amount mobilized, both the pub-
lic and private sectors have been important sources of capi-
tal. The largest category of innovative financing ($44 billion)
is public sector investments in the private sector through
mechanisms such as guarantees, which mobilize invest-
ment, and results-based financing mechanisms, through
which the public sector hires private companies to provide
public goods. Public investments in the public sector ($4
billion) occur through mechanisms such as debt-swaps and
dedicated levies. The private sector provides capital ($30
billion) to the public sector through voluntary and compul-
sory contributions and investments, such as bonds. The last
category, private sector investments in the private sector
($15 billion), captures resources from microfinance funds
and impact investing funds.
Most securities aim to provide risk-adjusted market
returns.
8
While mechanisms that offer below-market
returns remain an important part of the innovative financing
landscape, mechanisms that target risk-adjusted returns
are increasingly prominent. Bonds, which make up 30%
of the amount mobilized by innovative financing securities,
8 It is too early to determine the actual financial returns of many
innovative financing mechanisms. For this survey, we used targeted
returns.
Innovative Financing for Development: Scalable Business Models that Produce Economic, Social, and Environmental Outcomes6
Figure 6: Most innovative financing mechanisms support transfers between the public and private sectors
Private sector participation in innovative financing mechanisms, 2000-2013
Number of mechanisms (x-axis) and amount mobilized, USD million (y-axis) (n=278)
Invests capital (source)
280 260 240 220 180 160 120 140 60 80 20 40 200 100 0
15,000
Private Sector
(n=222)
Public Sector
(n=56)
Public Sector
45,500
Private Sector
30,500
44,300
48,100
3,800
Receives capital (use)
Source: Innovative Financing Initiative Database; Dalberg analysis.
Figure 7: The majority of instruments target risk-adjusted market returns
Target Financial Performance for Securities, Funds and Derivatives, 2000-2013
$ million (n=225)
Other investment
funds
(n=82)
0%
Loans
(n=4)
5,800
Other derivative
products
(n=8)
Guarantees
(n=17)
36,000 23,200
Microfinance
investment
funds (n=112)
Bonds
(n=14)
4%
1,800 9,100 600
Securities and Funds
Derivatives
Below Market Returns
Risk-Adjusted Market Returns
Source: Innovative Financing Initiative Database; Dalberg analysis.
CHAPTER 1: What is Innovative Financing? 7
are typically guaranteed by AAA rated international orga-
nizations. Returns vary with the issuing currency, and the
majority of bonds are issued in currencies with low volatil-
ity. Derivative products, including guarantees, tend to offer
below-market returns, but this is difficult to assess because
of the dominant role of the public sector.
Trends and Evolutions of Innovative
Financing Mechanisms
Since 2001, innovative financing for development has
experienced 11% annual growth. Starting at approxi-
mately $2 billion in 2001, the market has grown to nearly
$9 billion in 2012.
9
As shown in Figure 8, this reflects the
emergence of new instruments within the universe of
innovative financing, rather than the growth of existing
instruments. In particular, the emergence of microfinance
funds, thematic bonds, and auctions - such as the voluntary
carbon market - has driven most of the growth.
Market-based mechanisms that target risk-adjusted
returns have grown since 2001.
10
While mechanisms that
target below-market returns remain an important compo-
9 These calculations reflect a conservative estimate based on 137
mechanisms for which annual amounts were available.
10 Debt-swaps and buy-downs, donations as part of consumer purchases,
and taxes were excluded from this analysis.
nent of the landscape (53% of the total in 2012), there is an
increased focus on opportunities that target both social and
financial returns. There are two aspects of this trend. The
first aspect, from an investor perspective, is the emergence
of investments that offer risk-adjusted market returns. This
includes low-risk investments, such as green bonds that
are backed by development bank balance sheets, and more
risky propositions, such as microfinance funds and impact
investment funds. The second aspect, from an implementer
perspective, is the emergence of results-based financing
opportunities in which private companies and NGOs com-
pete to provide social goods.
The innovative financing market is still evolving—some
models have proven to be successful, some are ripe for
scaling, and others are still new ideas in the testing
stage. Proven models, such as guarantees and bonds, have
easily replicated and scaled structures, benefiting from
clear standards for assessing risk and determining payment
terms; many have established track records. Models that
are ripe for scaling, such as performance-based contracts,
are also easy to create, but do not have enough perfor-
mance data to establish a mature asset class. Newer ideas,
such as AMCs and DIBs, are still being developed and
will require substantial support from concessional donors
before they can attract private capital and scale beyond the
pilot stage.
Figure 8: Innovative financing has grown through the introduction of new instruments
0
11,000
10,000
9,000
8,000
7,000
6,000
5,000
4,000
3,000
2,000
1,000
12,000
13,000
Annual amount mobilized, 2001–2012
$ millions (n=278)
2012
Auctions
Performance-
based contracts
Awards and prizes
2011 2010
AMC
2009
Bonds
Investment funds
2008
Microfinance Funds
Loans
Consumer Donations
2007
Other derivative products
Taxes
2006
Guarantees
Debt-swaps and
buy-downs
2005 2004 2003 2002 2001
Note: Annual mobilized data was not available for 141 instruments. For these instruments, we assumed that the entire amount mobilized was mobilized in the
launch year.
Source: Innovative Financing Initiative Database; Dalberg analysis.
Innovative Financing for Development: Scalable Business Models that Produce Economic, Social, and Environmental Outcomes8
Figure 9: Innovative financing increasingly targets market returns
Resources mobilized for outcome-based solutions, 2000-2012
$ million (n=137)
2010 2011 2007
2006
2005
2004
2003
2002
2001
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
70%
80%
90%
100%
2009
2008
Results based finance
Below Market Returns
Risk-Adjusted Market Returns
Note: Debt-swaps and buy-downs, Donations as part of consumer purchases, and Taxes were excluded from this analysis
Source: Innovative Financing Initiative Database; Dalberg analysis.
Figure 10: Established instruments rely on standards and mobilize more resources
Landscape of innovative financing mechanisms
Taxes
Carbon Auctions
Consumer Donations
Simpler structures
Longer track record
Bonds and Notes
AMCs
Performance-based Contracts
Microfinance Funds
Debt-swaps/buy-downs Awards and Prizes
Loans
Other Investment Funds
Other Derivative Products
---Development Impact Bonds
Guarantees
Newer Ideas
Scaling Opportunities
Proven models
Bubble size = Total
$B mobilized
Note: No known Development Impact Bonds have been successfully issued to date although many are under development.
Source: Innovative Financing Initiative Database; Dalberg analysis.
CHAPTER 1: What is Innovative Financing? 9
Box 3: Characteristics of dierent market segments
Newer Ideas Opportunities to Scale Proven Models
Funds mobilized
to date
Less than USD 100 million or
only one instrument
Between USD 100 million and
USD one billion from multiple
instruments
Greater than USD one billion
from multiple instruments
Track record Little or none One or more clear success
stories since 2006
In use before 2006
Complexity Technically difficult to structure Structure may be complex, but
there are existing templates
Simpler structures or many pre-
existing templates
R&D cost High R&D cost and lengthy
development runway
Moderate R&D cost and
development runway
Relatively low R&D cost and
quick to launch
Stakeholder
coordination
Multiple stakeholders required
for success, across public/
private/civil sectors
Multiple stakeholders required
for success
Coordination needed for a few
stakeholders or stakeholders
within only one group
Applicability Potentially limited to only certain
applications
Many applications but still
limited number demonstrated
so far
Has been applied to many
sectors and asset classes
Examples • AMC (AMC for Pneumococcal)
• DIBs (Malaria in Mozambique
Performance Note)
• Impact Investing Funds (The
Global Health Investment
Fund)
• Performnce-Based Contracts
(Mexico PES)
• Microfinance
• Bond (WB Green Bond)
• Guarantees (DCA Guarantees)
Innovative Financing for Development: Scalable Business Models that Produce Economic, Social, and Environmental Outcomes10
CHAPTER 2:
How Does Innovative Financing Create Value?
Innovative financing mechanisms are tools to ad-
dress specific market failures and institutional barriers
that hinder global development. Innovative financing
mechanisms encompass a broad range of structures that
can allow investors, company managers, and government
officials to develop new strategies to address develop-
ment challenges. However, not all innovative financing
mechanisms are appropriate for every challenge. This
chapter highlights how different types of innovative financ-
ing solutions can produce positive outcomes and address
specific barriers.
Innovative financing instruments have been used to
produce a range of development outcomes. Innovative
financing has provided people in developing countries
access to goods, services, and capital. Microfinance
alone, for example, has provided loans to nearly a billion
people in 2012.
11
For private companies, innovative financing has been a
source of capital as well as a mechanism to create markets.
Guarantees enable investments, while performance-based
contracts create opportunities to deliver services. Financial
intermediaries have benefited primarily through access to
markets. For example, the market for green bonds is on
11 Source: MixMarket.com (accessed May 2014).
track to grow to $40 billion in 2014 through bonds issued
both by governments and corporations.
12
National governments and international donors have ben-
efited from innovative financing that funds public goods,
such as low-carbon infrastructure. Finally, innovative financ-
ing has also increased value for money within international
development, allowing donor agencies to achieve more
with the same—or fewer—resources. Figure 11 provides an
overview of how different innovative financing mechanisms
produce different outcomes for different actors. Bonds,
for example, provide capital for international donors, new
markets for financial intermediaries, and both capital and
public goods for national governments. The outcomes of
various innovative financing mechanisms are described in
more detail below.
Outcomes for Consumers and Private
Companies
Innovative financing has provided consumers with ac-
cess to essential goods and services and has provided
companies with access to markets. Successful innovative
financing mechanisms remove barriers to entry and enable
commercial investments in new products and markets.
12 Green Bonds Market Outlook 2014, Bloomberg New Energy Finance,
http://about.bnef.com/white-papers/green-bonds-market-outlook-2014/
(accessed June 2014)
CHAPTER 2: How Does Innovative Financing Create Value? 11
Typical barriers include: business models that are below
scale to be sustainably viable, market failures (such as lack
of information) that prevent the cost-effective delivery of
services, lack of facilities to manage and reallocate risk,
and inefficient markets that create high transaction costs.
Innovative financing mechanisms address these prob-
lems through resource mobilization, (e.g., driving invest-
ments as the microfinance industry became commercially
sustainable), financial intermediation, (e.g., reallocating
the business risk associated with producing health com-
modities), and improved resource delivery (e.g., sharing
information about new products such as product-linked
savings accounts.)
Case study 1: Access to essential health commodities
through Advance Market Commitments accelerates
the flow of capital to public goods that are not
economically viable without public support.
How it works: In an advance market commitment (AMC),
a buyer—typically a government or international organiza-
tion—agrees to a predetermined purchase price for a good
or service with a provider—typically a private company.
Originally, AMCs were conceived as a means to encourage
companies to invest in research and development for new
products, but it has also been used to increase production
for an existing product. Under the Pneumococcal AMC, for
example, donors pledged $1.5 billion to fund the subsidized
purchase of 2 billion doses of pneumococcal conjugate
vaccine (PCV) beginning in 2009.
13
In exchange for this
subsidy, manufacturers agreed to sell PCVs to low-income
countries at a price no greater than $3.50 for the next ten
years. As a point of comparison, the Pneumococcal AMC’s
prices for PCV are over 90% lower than those in high-
income markets.
13 As of December 2013, $652 million had been disbursed, which is the
number used to calculate amount mobilized in the database.
Figure 11: Innovative financing instruments produce a range of outcomes
Outcomes of selected innovative financing instruments for different stakeholders
Access to Markets Public Goods Access to Goods Access to Services Access to Capital Value for Money
Customers/
Beneficiaries
Performance-Based
Contracts
Bonds
Taxes and Levies
Guarantees
Microfinance
Advance Market
Commitments
Development
Impact Bonds
Impact Investing
Funds
Private
Companies
Financial
Intermediaries
National
Governments
International
Donors
Proven
Models
Opportunities
to Achieve
Scale
Experiments
and New
Ideas
Note: The outcomes for proven models have been demonstrated while outcomes for replication opportunities and new ideas are more theoretical.
Source: Dalberg analysis.
Pneumococcal AMC
Start Year:
2009
Amount
Mobilized:
$1.5 billion pledged
$652 billion disbursed to date
Investors:
y Italy ($635 million)
y UK ($485 million)
y Canada ( $200 million)
y The Russian Federation ($80 million)
y Norway ($50 million
y The Bill & Melinda Gates Foundation ($50
million).
Why is it
innovative:
The AMC created incentives for vaccine
research and production for developing
countries as donors commit funds to
guarantee the price of the vaccines once they
have been developed.
Innovative Financing for Development: Scalable Business Models that Produce Economic, Social, and Environmental Outcomes12
How it achieves outcomes: An effectively designed AMC
creates value for consumers by making essential goods
available and by lowering prices, and creates value for pro-
ducers by creating a market for the good. Ideally, the prede-
termined price for the good or service would be calibrated
so that the provider has incentives to produce the good but
does not earn excessive profits—but this calibration is dif-
ficult to achieve in practice. For example, the designers of
the Pneumococcal AMC did not (and could not) know the
necessary capital expenditure and unit costs of scaling up
production of the vaccine when they set the upfront sub-
sidy and purchase price. As a result, they established prices
that they believed would attract suppliers to the market
while maximizing value for money.
14
The Pneumococcal AMC was the first attempt to use
an AMC to accelerate the introduction of a vaccine in
developing countries. Since its launch, two suppliers -
GlaxoSmithKline (GSK) and Pfizer - have produced and
distributed 82 million doses of PCV to 24 low-income coun-
tries. While precise return data is not available, an indepen-
dent evaluation found that manufacturers likely earn returns
that are at or above 10-20% per year, which is consistent
with historic industry performance.
15
The AMC combined long-term commitments and tem-
porary subsidies to lower prices and create a market for
health commodities. Since its launch, participating suppliers
have expanded capacity and additional manufacturers have
expressed interest in joining the initiative. It is impossible to
know if the opportunity to provide the vaccine to millions of
people in new markets would have been enough to entice
low-cost manufacturers to participate without the advance
guarantee that vaccines would be purchased.
How it can be replicated: Beyond the pneumococcal
example, few AMCs have been considered as success-
ful in furthering development goals.
16
An AMC is a useful
innovative financing tool when private suppliers of goods or
services are involved, when providing the good or service
requires a high fixed-cost investment, and when demand
risk makes private companies reluctant to make the upfront
investment. However, when only these three criteria exist,
the AMC funder would typically find it more efficient to
14 See the pneumococcal AMC process and design evaluation (http://
www.gavialliance.org/results/evaluations/pneumococcal-amc-process-
design-evaluation/) for a more detailed discussion of the challenges of
designing the pneumococcal AMC.
15 (Chau, 2013)
16 In addition to the Pneumococcal AMC, there has been discussions of
using an AMC for rural energy in Rwanda and bioenergy in Sri Lanka.
offer a more traditional forward contract or a volume
guarantee with a single supplier. For example, power-
purchase agreements, in which a power purchaser (often
a state-owned utility) agrees to purchase energy from a
power utility for the next 10-20 years, are common tools
for financing electricity generating investments, including
renewable energy. Unlike advance market commitments,
power-purchase agreements do not aim to create a market
with multiple participants.
The more complex advance market commitment structure
is useful when the funders want to create a market in addi-
tion to providing a good and service. Specifically, AMCs are
well-suited for challenges with the following characteristics:
first, when private suppliers are not willing to be or cannot
be transparent about their costs. As a result, it is difficult
to determine the fair price that will attract new suppliers to
the market. Second, when payers can calculate a financial
benefit that allows them to set a price based on benefits
and not costs. This allows the donor that issues the AMC
to determine the ceiling of how much it is willing to pay to
induce market entry. Finally, AMCs are appropriate when
there is a benefit in having multiple companies compete for
the market rather than a funder partnering with one or two
organizations upfront. For some development challenges,
such as providing health commodities, donors will want to
work with multiple suppliers to avoid being dependent on
a single supplier. In other circumstances, such as provid-
ing electricity, the nature of the product requires a limited
number of suppliers.
Outcomes for National Governments
Innovative financing has attracted private resources
to fund development projects and public goods.
Successful innovative financing mechanisms create incen-
tives for private companies to invest in projects that benefit
people in developing countries, in particular people at the
base of the pyramid. These incentives include: enhancing
profit margins by blending capital from socially motivated
investors with more profit-oriented organizations, enhanc-
ing credit by shifting project risk to organizations with more
creditworthy balance sheets, and creating marketing op-
portunities by being associated with socially responsible in-
vestments. We provide examples of different mechanisms
that provide these incentives for private companies below.
Case study 2: Capital for investments in low-carbon
infrastructure through green bonds.
How it works: The World Bank first issued green bonds in
2008 to finance investments in low-carbon infrastructure,
CHAPTER 2: How Does Innovative Financing Create Value? 13
such as renewable energy infrastructure and energy ef-
ficiency improvements. In the past five years, green bonds
have grown considerably. According to Standard & Poor,
government and corporations issued $10.4 billion in green
bonds in 2013. A recent report by Bloomberg New Energy
Finance points out that the market is growing fast; at its
current pace, total volume of green bonds will surpass $40
billion by the end of 2014.
Green bonds have grown quickly because they can be eval-
uated using standard risk models, provide a risk-adjusted
return that meets investor expectations, and offer investors
the opportunity to be associated with a positive environ-
mental outcome.
17
To date, institutions with excellent credit
ratings and strong balance sheets have issued green bonds.
Notably, the yield for green bonds is the same as traditional
bonds offered by the same institution that are not dedicated
to low-carbon infrastructure.
How it achieves outcomes: Green bonds have suc-
cessfully channeled capital to low-carbon infrastructure,
which supports climate change mitigation and adaptation.
Furthermore, the use of green bonds by multinational cor-
porations suggests that this mechanism will scale beyond
the public sector and become a mainstream investment
product.
While the mainstreaming of green bonds is an impres-
sive achievement, given the lack of standards about what
constitutes a green investment, it is unclear how multina-
tional corporations will use the proceeds of these bonds.
This uncertainty presents a significant investment risk and,
if left unaddressed, might limit green bonds’ effective-
ness to raise funds that support development goals in the
future. Based on an independent review with the Center for
17 For example, a two-year green bond issued by the World Bank in August
2013 had an issue yield equivalent to a spread of +8.3 basis points over
a comparable U.S. Treasury.
World Bank
Green Bonds
Start Year:
2008
Amount
Mobilized:
$4.4 billion
Investors:
y Institutional investors (e.g., Blackrock, Calvert
Investments, Nikko Asset Management)
Pension Funds
y DFIs
y Government backed funds
Why is it
innovative:
Green bonds provide an instrument through
which investors who are concerned with
the effects of climate change can make a
difference by specifically supporting climate
change related projects.
Figure 12: The market for green bonds is growing
Growth in green bonds issued by select international finance institutions, 2008–2013
$ million
2010 2009
414
414
2008 2013 2011
2,735
889
726
267
595
2012
730
793
480
2,119
714
451
1,381
0
0
0
0
12
24
EBRD
World Bank
EIB
Source: Innovative Finance Initiative Database; Dalberg analysis.
Innovative Financing for Development: Scalable Business Models that Produce Economic, Social, and Environmental Outcomes14
International Climate and Environmental Research at the
University of Oslo (CICERO), the World Bank identified cri-
teria for projects that can be financed through green bonds
to mitigate the effects of climate change and help countries
adapt to the effects of climate change. In addition, 24 banks
have signed green bond principles that provide voluntary
guidelines on the use of proceeds, process for project
evaluation, management of proceeds, and reporting.
18
As
shown in Table 1, the criteria for green bonds is very broad.
In addition, while individual institutions monitor the use of
green bond proceeds and evaluate the effects, there are no
standard mechanisms to verify that the bonds are actually
used to finance green projects or to compare the environ-
mental benefits of different bonds.
How it can be replicated: Green bonds demonstrate the
potential of using the balance sheets of international fi-
nance institutions to channel capital to global priorities. The
concept does not need to be limited to environmental proj-
ects. It can be used when there is a need for investment
in global priorities that surpasses the current resources of
18 As of May 2014, the following institutions are members of the Green
Bond Principles: Banca IMI S.p.A., Banco Bilbao Vizcaya Argentaria
(BBVA), Banco Santander S.A., Bank of America Merrill Lynch, Barclays
Plc, BlackRock, Inc., BNP Paribas, California State Teachers’ Retirement
System (CalSTRS), Citi, Crédit Agricole CIB, Danske Bank A/S, DNB,
HSBC Bank Plc, International Financial Corporation (IFC), JP Morgan
Chase & Co, KBC Bank NV, Mitsubishi UFJ Securities International Plc,
Natixis, Natixis Asset Management—Mirova, Nomura International
Plc, Nordea Bank Finland Oyj, RBC Europe Ltd, Société Générale CIB,
Standish Mellon Asset Management Company LLC, The Royal Bank of
Scotland plc (RBS), TIAA-CREF, Westpac Institutional Bank, World Bank.
the public sector; and (2) the investments will generate ad-
equate cash flows through either profits or accrued savings
to repay the principal and interest on the bonds.
A similar approach was used by the International Finance
Facility for Immunisation (IFFIm) to mobilize resources and
streamline the deployment of funds for vaccines. Similar
to sovereign bonds, the IFFIm governments make a legally
binding commitment to repay bonds sold to institutional
and individual investors. To date, the IFFIm has raised $4.5
billion at costs similar to those of the World Bank, proving
that this structure can efficiently raise capital.
Case study 3: Capital for investments in technology
innovations through impact investing
How it works: Since the term was first used in 2007,
impact investing has emerged as an innovative approach to
producing both social and financial returns. Impact investing
is an approach to select, manage, and measure the impact
of investments that produce a social and environmental
good. As show in Figure 1, most impact investing focuses
on sectors that produce social returns such as agricul-
ture, healthcare, and financial services. Impact investing
channels investments in established asset classes such
as private equity, debt, convertible debt instruments, and
guarantees, with a focus on companies in either growth or
venture stages.
19
19 (World Economic Forum, 2013)
Table 1: Comparison of World Bank and Green Bond Principles Criteria
Category Example World Bank Criteria
Green Bond Principles
Usage Guidelines*
Mitigation
Solar and wind electricity generation (Renewable energy)
New technologies to reduce greenhouse gas emissions
Rehabilitation of power plants to reduce emissions
Increased transport efficiency
Waste management and construction of energy-efficient buildings
Reforestation and avoided deforestation
Clean Drinking Water
Adaptation
Protection against flooding
Food security improvements and sustainable agriculture
Sustainabe forest management
Biodiversity conservation
*Green Bond Principles use of proceeds is not limited to these examples.
Source: World Bank, Green Bond Principles (2014); Dalberg analysis.
CHAPTER 2: How Does Innovative Financing Create Value? 15
Impact investing can also attract capital to promising in-
novations, such as research and development for health
vaccines. The Global Health Investment Fund, for example,
uses public and philanthropic guarantees to attract private
investors (including high net worth individuals, institu-
tional investors, and strategic investors) to fund medical
research and development that will lead to the eradication
of preventable diseases in low-income countries. It offers
investors a fixed return of 2% per year, as well as 80% of
any return made by the fund, and a partial guarantee from
the Bill and Melinda Gates Foundation and Sida for up to
60% of their invested capital.
How it achieves outcomes: The fund has successfully
raised $108 million, but it is too early to assess if it will
deliver new technologies. As of August 2014, it has made
two investments: a $8 million investment in a tuberculosis
diagnostics technology and a $5 million investment in a
new oral cholera vaccine.
How it can be replicated: Impact investing encompasses
a broad range of approaches and can be used whenever an
investor wants to focus on social, environmental, econom-
ic, and financial returns. Within the context of innovative
financing, it is particularly useful for:
• Providing capital to companies that struggle to access
capital, but produce important benefits for broader
society. For example, small and medium enterprises are
important drivers of employment but frequently struggle
to raise the capital necessary to grow.
• Providing capital to early stage ventures that support
innovation. Impact investors can combine social and
financial returns by focusing investments on innovative
approaches to global challenges, such as the Global
Health Investment Fund’s focus on new vaccines.
Case study 4: Credit enhancements to support
economic development through guarantees
How it works: Political risk insurance issued by public
institutions is an important component of international de-
velopment. The World Bank Multilateral Investment Agency
(MIGA) promotes foreign direct investment by insuring
projects against losses related to currency inconvertibility,
Global Health
Investment Fund
Start Year:
2013
Amount
Mobilized:
$108 Million
Investors:
y High-net-worth Individuals
y Foundations (Bill and Melinda Gates Founda-
tion, Childrens Investment Fund Foundation)
y Institutional investors (AXA Investment Man-
agers, JPMorgan Chase & Co , Storebrand)
y Strategic investors (GlaxoSmithKline (GSK),
Merck & Co, The Pfizer Foundation)
y Government-backed funds (German Develop-
ment Bank (KfW), and Swedish International
Development Cooperation Agency (Sida))
Why is it
innovative:
GHIF mobilized resources by combining
government and private guarantees to leverage
private investment for research for new
vaccines.
Figure 13: Impact investing focuses on social sectors
30%
31%
36%
43%
44%
45%
47%
51%
57%
Investment focus of impact investing funds, by sector
Percent of Survey Respondents
Education
Food and Agriculture
Water and Sanitation
Other
Healthcare
Financial Services (excluding Microfinance)
Information and Communication Technology
Housing
Energy
Note: Respondents chose all that apply.
Source: GIIN, J.P. Morgan (January 2013).
Innovative Financing for Development: Scalable Business Models that Produce Economic, Social, and Environmental Outcomes16
expropriation, war and civil disturbance, and non-honoring
of financial obligations.
While MIGA is an important facilitator of finance, it is
not a novel institution and providing political risk insur-
ance is not a new idea. Since providing its first guarantee
in 1990, MIGA has issued over 1,100 guarantees that
total $30 billion.
20
Over time, its exposure has shifted
from Latin America and the Caribbean to Sub-Saharan
Africa, reflecting both a change in policy as well as new
market opportunities.
20 MIGA 2013 Annual Report. http://www.miga.org/documents/Annual_
Report13.pdf
How it achieves outcomes: MIGAs mission is to promote
investment in emerging markets. It creates value by lower-
ing the cost of borrowing compared to commercial offer-
ings or by creating new instruments, such as long-tenor
loans. By bearing some of the risk of cross-border invest-
ments, it supports investments in emerging markets that
create jobs and drive economic growth. It can achieve this
goal directly through its own operations or indirectly by ex-
posing the mispricing of risk and demonstrating that private
sector insurers can profitably offer insurance in emerging
markets through products that go beyond commercial risk.
According to an independent evaluation, MIGA chan-
neled an estimated $56 billion of investments in high-
and medium-risk countries between 1990 and 2007. Its
guarantees are important mechanisms that allow invest-
ments in emerging countries to be approved by credit and
risk committees.
How it can be replicated: It is not clear that MIGA offers
a replicable model. MIGA, through its association with the
World Bank, is a unique institution that has the ability to ap-
ply enormous political pressure when assessing claims. It
has paid only six claims in its history. It is profitable. While
these characteristics suggest good risk management, they
World Bank: Multilateral
Investment Agency (MIGA)
Start Year:
1988
Amount
Mobilized:
$30 Billion
Investors:
y Issued by the World Bank
y Reinsurance provided by insurance compa-
nies when necessary
Why is it
innovative:
MIGA mitigates political risks that prevent
private sector investment in developing
countries by providing political risk insurance.
Figure 14: MIGA exposure has shifted to Sub-Saharan Africa
3.61.1 1.7 1.81.51.2 2.71.71.4 1.31.21.70.80.70.70.50.30.20.2
MIGA Gross Exposure by Region, 1990-2013
$ billion, 3-year rolling average
1999 to 2001
1.7
1998 to 2000
1.3
1997 to 1999
0.9
1996 to 1998
2002 to 2004
Sub-Saharan Africa
Middle East & North Africa
South Asia
East Asia & Pacific
Latin America & Caribbean
2011 to 2013
Europe & Central Asia
1995 to 1997
1994 to 1996
1993 to 1995
1992 to 1994
1991 to 1993
1990 to 1992
2007 to 2009
2005 to 2007
2006 to 2008
2003 to 2005
2010 to 2012
2009 to 2011
2008 to 2010
2001 to 2003
2000 to 2002
2004 to 2006
Source: MIGA Project Database; Dalberg analysis
Source: MIGA Project Database; Dalberg analysis.
CHAPTER 2: How Does Innovative Financing Create Value? 17
Figure 15: Political risk is perceived as a barrier to investment and demand for investment insurance is growing
Major constraints to foreign investments
over the next three years, 2010–2013
Percent
2013
Macroeconomic instability
Lack of qualified staff
4%
2012
Limited Size of the Market
2011
Poor Infrastructure
2010
100%
Other
Political risk
W
eak government institutions
Lack of financing
New Investment Insurance Volumes,
Berne Union, 2008–2012
$ billion
97%
4%
59
MIGA
Other members
of the Berne Union
2009 2010
97%
3%
96%
3%
2%
97%
49
66
98%
2008
94
2012 2011
3%
75
21%
16%
18%
15%
20% 21%
22% 19%
10%
5%
19%
9%
9%
11%
7%
7%
11%
13%
11%
17%
18%
18%
13%
13%
8% 10%
5%
7%
5%
7%
8%
Major constraints to foreign investments
over the next three years, 2010–2013
Percent
2013
Macroeconomic instability
Lack of qualified staff
4%
2012
Limited Size of the Market
2011
Poor Infrastructure
2010
100%
Other
Political risk
Weak government institutions
Lack of financing
New Investment Insurance Volumes,
Berne Union, 2008–2012
$ billion
97%
4%
59
MIGA
Other members
of the Berne Union
2009 2010
97%
3%
96%
3%
2%
97%
49
66
98%
2008
94
2012 2011
3%
75
21%
16%
18%
15%
20% 21%
22% 19%
10%
5%
19%
9%
9%
11%
7%
7%
11%
13%
11%
17%
18%
18%
13%
13%
8% 10%
5%
7%
5%
7%
8%
Source: World Investment and Political Risk, 2013, MIGA; Dalberg analysis. Source: Berne Union, 2008-2012 Statistics; MIGA Annual Report 2013 and
2012; Dalberg analysis.
Figure 16: Long-term political risk insurance is becoming more widely available
590
515
705
630
415
350 350
2010
Political Risk Market Capacity by Tenor, 2010-2013
Total possible maximum per year, $ million
2013 2010 2013
380
10-year Project Risk 15-year Trade Risk (political)
970
540
415
+9%
+6%
10-year Trade Risk (political)
+22%
+23%
2010 2010
15-year Project Risk
440 440
320
370
2013 2013
710
Source: Gallagher London, PRI Report and Market Updates 2010 to 2013; Dalberg analysis.
Innovative Financing for Development: Scalable Business Models that Produce Economic, Social, and Environmental Outcomes18
also reflect the influence that the World Bank can have in
resolving disputes before they become formal claims.
Nevertheless, given the high demand for political risk
insurance, it is an opportunity for new market entrants.
The tenor of guarantees offered by private re-insurers are
extending and are approaching those offered by MIGA. As
shown in Figure 16, the maximum amount insured per risk
has increased in recent years. This change could serve as a
model for private sector provision of other financial interme-
diation services within the development space.
Outcomes for International Donors
Innovative financing makes donors’ delivery of interna-
tional assistance more effective and efficient. Financial
markets function because the price of an asset commu-
nicates information about its value. There is no analogous
concept in development, however. It is difficult to assess
the value of an education program, less pollution, or bet-
ter health outcomes. Structures that enable collaboration
between development funders and service providers align
incentives by assigning a value to development outcomes
and creating a market to provide those services. As a
result, intended beneficiaries have more influence over
the services they receive and the private sector is more
likely to compete to deliver social goods and create more
efficient solutions.
Case Study 5: New business models that create
opportunities for community development through
development impact bonds
How it works: Development impact bonds (DIBs) pool mul-
tiple performance-based contracts and turn social problems
into investible opportunities. They differ from standard
grant mechanisms because investor returns are based on
the achievement of a pre-determined outcome. Despite its
label, DIBs are not bonds. While they have capped returns
like fixed-income investments, DIBs also share characteris-
tics with equity investments since neither the principal nor
coupon payments are guaranteed.
While there is no standard structure, DIBs frequently
involve investors that provide capital at the beginning of
the project, outcome funders that provide financing if the
project succeeds, and a fund manager that allocates capital
to achieve development goals. Critically, they also include
a framework for monitoring and evaluation to determine if
the service provider is successful. Figure 17 provides one
possible structure. In this structure for a three-year bond
without a coupon, only 50% of the principal is guaranteed.
If the projects funded achieve the predetermined metrics at
bond maturity, the outcome funder will repay the investor
the full principal with a 5% annualized return. The manager
of the SPV and the service provider would also receive
performance bonuses in addition to upfront payments.
How it achieves outcomes: DIBs are still in a nascent
stage. Few have mobilized resources and internationally
oriented DIBs do not have long enough track records to
assess outcomes. They seek, however, to align incentives
between various actors, promote risk transparency, and
encourage innovation.
• Aligning incentives. The dynamics of international
development differ from many markets because the
entity that pays for a good or service—typically a donor
or philanthropy—is different from the entity that enjoys
the good or service—typically a recipient government or
individual. This situation limits the information available
to the funder and impedes an efficient market. A DIB’s
structure transfers the risk of providing the service from
the funder to the service provider and investor. As a
result, DIBs work best for new approaches to providing
goods and services. If the service provider and investor
have a new way of achieving the outcome, they can po-
tentially earn more than if they funded the same project
through grants. As a result, for the DIB market to grow,
it will have to resemble a venture capital model in which
well-informed and experienced investors have the ability
to evaluate these new innovations.
• Promoting transparency. The investors and outcome
funders negotiate terms that reflect the probability of
success (from the investors perspective) and the abil-
ity to extract potential efficiencies (from the outcome
funder’s perspective).
21
By establishing a price for the
bond, beliefs about perceived risk are made transparent,
because both the output funder and the investor need
to calculate the level of risk.
• Encouraging innovation. The output funder does not
specify the method for achieving the desired outcome,
which allows the service provider to deploy innovative
approaches and to tailor the intervention to local situ-
ations. The implementer may, however, receive assis-
tance from the investor, for example, through perfor-
mance management systems or feedback loops; after
all, it is in the investors interest to help the implementer
succeed so that the investor receives his premium.
21 Both of these factors are difficult to estimate ex-ante and create
ambiguity in the negotiation process.
CHAPTER 2: How Does Innovative Financing Create Value? 19
How it can be replicated: Given their risks, likely low
returns, and lack of performance history, DIBs will initially
appeal to traditional donors and philanthropies. Commercial
investors may become more interested once the model is
proven successful or if there is a significant guarantee. In
order to make DIBs “investable opportunities,” outcome
funders will incur additional costs compared to funding
investment up-front (unless the investor has a lower cost
of capital than the outcome funder, which is unlikely). Even
social impact investors who merely aim to preserve capital
will require interest rates that compensate them for the risk
of a service provider failing to achieve the outcome targets.
Figure 17: Illustrative cash flows of a Development Impact Bond
Investor Service Provider(s)
Initial Payment Guaranteed Payment Contingent Payment
50
95
5
Monetizeable Savings and Social Benefits
50
100
66
Positive
Externalities
Outcome Funder
Guarantor
(if necessary)
Credit
Enhancement
3 YEAR | ZERO COUPON
Special Purpose Vehicle
Potential Cash flows At issue
At maturity
(guaranteed)
At maturity
(If metrics are achieved)
Investor -100 +50 +66
Outcome Funder 0 -50 -75
Special Purpose
Vehicle
+5 0 +4
Projects +95 0 +5
75
Note: Cash flows are for illustrative purposes only. Some DIBs have no guaranteed payments
Source: Dalberg analysis.
Innovative Financing for Development: Scalable Business Models that Produce Economic, Social, and Environmental Outcomes20
CHAPTER 3:
What Are The Next Steps For Innovative Financing?
Opportunities
The focus of innovative financing is shifting from
mobilizing resources to delivering positive social and
environmental outcomes through market-based instru-
ments. In the past ten years, the growth of the innovative
financing sector has come from the emergence of new
mechanisms such as thematic bonds, microfinance, and re-
sults-based financing. These mechanisms are market-based
structures that effectively align incentives and increase
focus on tangible outcomes.
Based on historic growth rates, we project innovative
financing will grow to $24 billion per year by 2020.
22
This estimate is likely conservative, given increasing pres-
sure from governments, investors, and citizens to produce
tangible environmental and social results. Additionally, our
estimate does not include the recent increase in activity by
corporates that issue green bonds, the potential for invest-
ment in infrastructure, or the potentially rapid rise of new
22 We expect an annual average growth rate for the entire sector
of approximately 12% per year, but can vary from 3% per year
for derivative products excluding guarantees to 17% per year for
performance based contracts. Growth rates and other assumptions
used to make projections for each type of instruments are included in
Annex 1.
donors, such as those in China. Most importantly, it does
not reflect efforts to relax the constraints affecting the in-
novative financing market (discussed below). Nevertheless,
the estimate accounts for several trends that will likely
shape the innovative financing sector between now and
2020, such as:
• Increased use of established instruments by new
participants. Innovative financing mechanisms that
have already received widespread acceptance, such as
guarantees and thematic bonds, will grow as commer-
cial investors and private companies incorporate them
into their capital allocation strategies. There is a need
to establish standards around how these products can
be used. Based on our experience with microfinance,
we have seen that while commercial investors enable
long-term sustainability, their involvement can also have
unintended consequences such as providing capital to
projects or individuals who will not be able to repay the
loan or distorting markets. Establishing guidelines for
how green bonds—or other thematic bonds—can use
proceeds to produce positive environmental outcomes
will likely reduce the chance that these funds are
used inappropriately.
CHAPTER 3: What Are the Next Steps for Innovative Financing? 21
•
Expansion of successful pilots into new markets. The
public sector can build on mechanisms that worked in
one sector, and deploy them in new sectors. Promising
mechanisms of this sort include advance market com-
mitments, results-based financing, and impact invest-
ing. There is a need for investors—particularly investors
with a dual social and financial mandate—to sponsor
opportunities in new markets.
• Continued innovation within development by creat-
ing new products. The public sector will continue to
develop and promote newer mechanisms such as
development impact bonds. The creation of these types
of mechanisms is an important part of the innovative
financing market.
Constraints
The current innovative financing market structure
impedes potential growth. Constraints limit the supply of
finance, weaken demand for new mechanisms or expan-
sion of existing mechanisms to new markets, and impede
the matchmaking between the two. Addressing these con-
straints could increase the market size substantially from
the currently projected $24 billion per year growth trajec-
tory. In particular, the barriers below hinder the growth of
innovative financing.
Supply Challenges
Opaque language and limited understanding of inno-
vative financing business models, operating environ-
ments, and different actors’ institutional constraints
reduce the supply of capital. Many current mecha-
nisms—particularly those still in the nascent stage—fail
to offer risk-return profiles that fit investor requirements.
It is always difficult to assess risks associated with new
instruments, but the use of inconsistent language makes it
difficult for development practitioners and financial manag-
ers to clearly communicate. For example, development
impact bonds, which do not guarantee the repayment of
the principal and offer a higher return when metrics are
achieved, have more in common with equity investments
than bonds. Current mechanisms lack the clear and compel-
ling product definition and risk-adjusted returns that private
sector investors require. The market would benefit from
a clear segmentation that clarifies which products could
appeal to commercially oriented donors and which ones
will require temporary subsidies to establish the necessary
performance history.
Few institutions have the capacity, mandate, or experi-
ence with innovative financing vehicles necessary to
create new products or to evaluate the risks of exist-
ing ones. Large institutional investors have a fiduciary
responsibility to achieve risk-adjusted returns that align with
Figure 18: The focus of innovative financing is changing
Public goods related to
health, environment and
infrastructure
Targeted investment opportunities
within agriculture, energy and
infrastructure
Time
Size of sector
TODAY
Experimentation with
market-based instruments
grow the market
Outcomes-based finance
attracts private capital
Aid-based pilots mobilize
resources
Engagement of customers,
investors, corporations and
governments in emerging
markets
Taxes, levies and voluntary private
contributions
Foreign-based investment funds,
public-partnerships, and solutions
to address political constraints
Risk sharing and incentives to
mobilize private enterprises and local
investors
Mechanisms:
1995–2005 2005–2015 2015–2030
Innovative Financing for Development: Scalable Business Models that Produce Economic, Social, and Environmental Outcomes22
investor expectations. While many large investors believe
that responsible investing can produce financial returns and
reduce reputational risk, they are not willing to sacrifice
financial return for social benefits. This reluctance restricts
the supply of capital to opportunities in which financial and
social returns are correlated.
From a public sector perspective, many large donor agen-
cies do not have the legal authority and institutional incen-
tives to pursue innovative financing schemes. Many donors
make investment decisions based on annual appropriations,
which limits their ability to make long-term commitments.
They also often do not have the authority to make invest-
ments with contingent liabilities or equity. While multilateral
financial institutions (such as the World Bank) and bilateral
institutions with a private sector mandate (such as Proparco
in France and the CDC group in the UK) have greater flex-
ibility, innovative financing remains a relatively small portion
of government aid.
Finally, innovative financing product sponsors’ failure to
engage with a broad part of the financial sector further
limits capital and expertise. Certain providers of financial
services, such as private banking and private equity, have
offered impact investing and microfinance investments.
However, other types of financial institutions, such as insur-
ance companies and pension fund managers, have only
explored innovative financing in a limited capacity. Within
financial institutions, there has also been very little engage-
ment with the credit and risk assessment departments to
learn how to evaluate new innovative financing vehicles—
this lack of involvement limits the supply of capital and
does not tap the departments’ expertise, which is neces-
sary to develop new products.
Intermediation Challenges
Lack of standards, data, liquidity, and performance
metrics makes it difficult for investors to assess innova-
tive financing opportunities. Clear, comprehensive, and
credible performance information will allow commercial
investors to participate in the market. In the case of green
bonds and microfinance, for example, the availability of
standardized information about the mechanisms’ financial
performance has enabled investors to participate in these
markets. However, it is difficult to gather this information
for many other types of innovative financing mechanisms.
In addition, while organizations such as the Global Impact
Investing Network (GIIN) have made considerable efforts
to provide standard metrics for assessing the develop-
ment impact of these investments, there is still no way to
compare the social, environmental, and economic results of
different investments.
With the notable exception of bonds and microfinance,
innovative financing instruments do not have the
market infrastructure necessary to create liquidity. The
Figure 19: Innovative financing mechanisms are projected to mobilize $24 billion per year by 2020 based on his-
torical performance
Estimated amounts mobilized annually by innovative financing mechanisms
$ million
2,200
4,400
0 2,000
1,800
1,800
1,000
1,000
900
4,000 6,000 8,000 10,000 12,000
5,000
Guarantees 11,000
Impact Investing Funds
900 Taxes/Levies
100
100
30
0
Consumer purchases 50
Microfinance Investment Funds
6,000
Thematic Bonds
Development Impact Bonds 200
3,000
600
1,100
Advanced Market Commitments
Debt-swaps and buy-downs
Other derivative products
10
500
Performance-based contracts
Auctions
7,000
2,000
Proven
Models
Opportunities
to Scale
New Ideas
Source: Innovative Financing Initiative estimates based on historic performance.
CHAPTER 3: What Are the Next Steps for Innovative Financing? 23
heterogeneous and bespoke nature of many innovative fi-
nancing mechanisms prevents investors from trading prod-
ucts to create liquidity in the market. A common infrastruc-
ture, such as credit rating agencies and exchanges, would
help facilitate the trading of products to increase liquidity.
Demand Challenges
A lack of investment in design funding limits innova-
tion and increases the costs associated with introduc-
ing new instruments. Creating new innovative financing
mechanisms—especially mechanisms without track re-
cords—can be very costly. The GAVI Alliance, for example,
provided more than $30 million to the Pneumococcal
Vaccines Accelerated Development and Introduction
Plan (PneumoADIP) to build the business case for the
Pneumococcal AMC. Microfinance required decades of
grants and concessional finance before it became a com-
mercially viable investment. Creating new mechanisms also
takes a significant amount of time. Designing the IFFIm
required the UK Government, the World Bank, Goldman
Sachs, and the lawyers for GAVI to work together for over
two years. Likewise, the Global Health Investment Fund, an
impact investing fund that supports research and develop-
ment for new vaccines, spent over two years raising capi-
tal, despite having guarantees from the Gates Foundation
and the Norwegian government. Without significant upfront
support, innovative financing mechanisms often operate at
below scale and fail to achieve their potential.
Proposed Solutions and Roles for
Different Actors
Public and private actors must work together to ac-
celerate the growth of the innovative financing mar-
ket. We have identified three ways to support the market
growth, described in more detail below. First, organizations
that design and implement innovative financing mecha-
nisms can make greater efforts to share knowledge and
learn from each other. Better information about the financial
and social performance of innovative financing products
will attract new actors. Second, new partners can provide
capital and expertise. In particular, institutions than manage
capital for private investors can actively seek investments
and development practitioners can create opportunities that
meet the investment criteria and requirements of those
investors. Third, there is a need to reduce the start-up costs
and transaction costs of new innovative financing mecha-
nisms. New mechanisms can adopt successful strategies
from existing efforts, but learning from past efforts requires
increased transparency and more systematic monitoring
and evaluation of performance.
1. Share knowledge and learn about innovative financ-
ing through a central resource for technical assis-
tance, data, and tools. Innovative financing consists of
a heterogeneous collection of asset classes that behave
differently under varying market conditions and are gov-
erned by different sets of rules and regulations. There are
no standardized ways to describe performance, and this
Box 4: Potential for growth in dierent sectors
Global Health: Innovative financing in health has mobilized over $8.2 billion total since 2006. By 2020, an additional $18 billion may be
mobilized for innovative financing mechanisms in global health.
a
In addition to the previously tested models, several additional areas
are ripe for innovative financing. These include mHealth (mobile platforms for collecting data, technology platforms for education and
diagnostics), new diagnostic tools, nutrition (micronutrients and biofortification), and reproductive health (e.g., long term birth control
solutions).
Agriculture and Food Security: Innovative financing in agriculture and food security has mobilized approximately $1 billion over the last
three years. At the current investment pace, the opportunity for innovative financing mechanisms would reach an additional $2.5 billion
total by 2020. A number of mechanisms in agriculture and food security have focused on accelerating access to capital. In addition, new
innovative financing mechanisms could include improved inputs (biofortified crops, improved crop yields through plant breeding and
open pollinated crop development, fertilizer with reduced waste and run-off), innovation in harvest and storage (improved on-farm stor-
age technology or improved drying and processing technology), and improved ICT service to enable market transactions.
Climate, Environment, and Energy: Various innovative financing mechanisms and funds have mobilized over $17.4 billion in the sector
since 2007. Based on growth rates from 2007-2013, the opportunity for climate and environment related innovative financing could
be as high as an additional $45 billion by 2020. Additional areas ripe for innovative financing include: green community development
innovations such as new green building materials, energy efficient transport systems such as vehicle sharing or electric scooters, and
household-level innovations such as improved or advanced technology for off-grid cooking (especially cook stoves), and lighting and solar
innovation.
a Based on the assumption that non-IFFIm funding grows at maximum historical 2006-2011 CAGR, and IFFIm funding remains stable at historical 2006-2013
average size.
Innovative Financing for Development: Scalable Business Models that Produce Economic, Social, and Environmental Outcomes24
information is rarely publically available. As a result, it is
difficult to compare performance across different assets
and identify mechanisms that most effectively produce
development outcomes. In addition, a broader under-
standing of how different types of innovative financing
mechanisms can address specific problems would help
push the sector forward.
2. Engage new partners by promoting asset classes
that attract profit-oriented managers and investors.
Engaging the private sector will require new approaches
to creating bankable products. These products may
include public sector investments in supportive policies
and regulation, risk capital, and knowledge. Promising op-
portunities that produce social and financial returns and
that identify innovative and more efficient ways to deliver
goods and services will entice private sector actors. An
initial opportunity, for example, could be the expansion of
thematic bonds from the environmental sector to other
development areas such as health and education. Like
green bonds, these bonds would be issued by interna-
tional finance institutions and would mobilize private sec-
tor capital in a manner consistent with existing business
models and asset requirements. These opportunities
would create channels for the financial industry to partici-
pate in investments that produce social returns.
3. Finally, support the development of promising and
proven products by collaborating during the design
phase. The current approach for developing new innova-
tive financing products is costly and time consuming.
Often, the public sector champions new products that
do not take into account the business needs of poten-
tial investors. A channel for private sector institutions
to participate on their terms during the early stages of
product design would help overcome the obstacle of
differing priorities. Creating a public-private partnership
will reduce transaction costs associated with launching
new products and will build coalitions of organizations
that are committed to growing the sector. Public funders
would specify what will be achieved by articulating
a limited number of objectives and proposing incen-
tives to catalyze private investment. Financial inter-
mediaries would determine how to attract capital and
achieve those objectives.
Increased use of innovative financing mechanisms will
require greater coordination between different actors.
For example:
• Regulators and Policymakers can ensure that country
laws allow innovative financing funding mechanisms
and actively seek opportunities to collaborate around
new innovative financing mechanisms.
• Foundations and NGOs can fund research to identify
appropriate opportunities for new mechanisms and host
events to facilitate collaborations around specific new
mechanisms.
• Development Banks and Impact Investors can invest
in promising but unproven ideas, provide guarantees,
Box 5: Challenges vary by sector
Sample barriers and challenges for engaging private sector players in the sector (not exhaustive)
Agriculture
• Lack of credit history and collateral implies a high risk for lenders
• Complex risk profile due to agronomic and political risks
• Low demand for financing among SHF due to high risk evaluation
Education
• Importance of scale (low margins)
• Few exit options
• High risk due to long time horizon and lack of collateral
Energy and
environment
• Difficulty of measurement of impact
• Difficulty in getting to scale
• Uncertainty related to the political environment
Health
• High leve of uncoordinated action within the sector
• High risk in the early product development phase
• Limited exit options, and reputational risks when exiting
Infrastructure
• Lack of understanding and capacity to structure projects
• Complex risk exposure (e.g., related to cross-border investments)
• Lack of transparent regulatory frameworks and legal security
CHAPTER 3: What Are the Next Steps for Innovative Financing? 25
and promote the use of standards to measure and com-
municate social and financial performance.
• Financial Intermediaries can identify promising op-
portunities that produce social and financial returns,
communicate the needs of different types of investors
to policy makers, and provide liquidity to create markets.
• Institutional Investors can provide capital to invest-
ments that provide risk-adjusted returns and actively
seek opportunities to collaborate around new innovative
financing mechanisms.
• Private companies can seek innovative and more effi-
cient ways to deliver goods and services and participate
in public-private partnerships
Conclusion
Meeting global commitments to eradicate poverty and
to respond to climate change will require all possible
sources of financing. Identifying new opportunities for
funding requires collaboration between different actors—
especially investors, entrepreneurs, and policy-makers.
Innovative financing provides a set of tools for donors who
want to create more development impact through their
investments, corporations open to new business models
in new markets, and financial institutions looking for new
opportunities.
Innovative financing is a critical tool to engage the pri-
vate sector and increase the international communitys
focus on development outcomes. Innovative financing
is a bridge that enables the transition from grant-funding
models to structures that support markets and promote
long-term sustainability. Innovative financing can attract
private companies that want to expand into new markets,
investors and fund managers who want to produce both
financial and social returns, and governments that want to
achieve more and better development impact in a resource-
constrained environment.
There is an opportunity and need to accelerate the
growth of bankable investments that mobilize re-
sources for development and increase the efficiency
and effectiveness of financial flows. To capitalize on
this opportunity, the status quo needs to change: many
potential sources of capital and expertise remain untapped,
and new innovative financing mechanisms often fail to
account for the existing business models, incentives, and
constraints of investors and private business. In addition,
the innovative financing market is still very conservative;
bonds and guarantees dominate the market by shifting the
risk from private to public investors. The more innovative
mechanisms that do exist often only involve a small set of
actors or target specific issues. Further innovative financing
opportunities are often missed because few players have
the context and credibility to “translate between” public
finance institutions, private players, and local governments.
Increasing the use of innovative financing will require
a coordinated effort from public and private partners.
This coordinated effort will need to increase informa-
tion and transparency on innovative finance successes
and failures, demonstrate scalable models to enable
innovative finance and build a global network of inves-
tors and entrepreneurs to expand the sector. By combin-
ing private sector approaches to achieving risk-adjusted
returns with a philanthropic orientation to producing social
impact, the international community can harness innova-
tive financing to address global economic, social, and
environmental challenges.
Box 6: Proposals to accelerate the creation of innovative financing products
Description Deliverables
The Innovative
Financing
Exchange
The Innovative Financing Exchange will
provide technical assistance, build capacity for
negotiations, and support data measurement
and outcomes.
Date: Gather and publish annual performance data
Tools: Create and share a risk management framework
Advice: Support practitioners creating new products
Innovative
Financing
Structuring and
Marketing Group
The Innovative Financing Structuring and
Marketing Group is a public-private partnership
to identify and replicate models that work and
use them in new sectors and markets.
Identify three scalable models and work with public
and private partners to mobilize additional resources.
Innovative
Finance Incubator
The innovative financing incubator will support
the design and development of new products to
test approaches and partnerships.
A co-funding facility to support new innovative
financing products.
Source: Dalberg analysis and expert interviews.
Innovative Financing for Development: Scalable Business Models that Produce Economic, Social, and Environmental Outcomes26
ANNEX 1:
METHODOLOGY AND DEFINITIONS
Data collection approach
The data used in this report is a conservative estimate
of the innovative financing market. We used Annex 9
(Glossary of Selected Innovative and Traditional Financial
Instruments and Mechanisms) in Navin Girishankar,
Innovating Development Finance, From Financing Sources
to Financial Solutions World Bank Policy Research Working
Paper 5111, November 2009) as a starting point and com-
plemented it with additional desk research. In particular, we
drew upon surveys of innovative financing by the OECD,
and the Leading Group on Innovative Financing. In addition,
we drew on data collected by the Global Impact Investment
Network (GIIN) to capture information about microfinance
and other investment funds.
To determine whether or not an instrument should be
included, we asked three questions.
• Maturity and Scope: Did the instrument mobilize re-
sources for a developing country? We started with a list
of 14 types of instruments that commonly referred to as
innovative financing. These instruments and our defini-
tions of them are provided below. We did not include
institutions (such as the Global Alliance for Vaccines or
Immunizations), generic fundraising approaches (such
as crowd funding sites), or financial flows between indi-
viduals (such as remittances). We also limited the scope
to transfers between countries. As a result, we did not
include instruments such as the Social Impact Bonds
in the UK and the US because those use domestic re-
sources for domestic purposes or the important growth
in resources within developing countries.
• Innovation: Did the instrument introduce a new product,
facilitate entry into new market, or attract new partici-
pants? As discussed above, innovation is in the eye of
the beholder. In determining whether or not an instru-
ment is innovative, we adopted a very broad definition
of innovation. This is consistent with how international
organizations implicitly defined the market.
• Intention: Did the sponsors of the instrument intend to
produce positive social and environmental outcomes?
We recognize that many types of international resource
flows, including foreign direct investment and remittanc-
es, have positive development effects. For the purpose
of this study, we limited our scope to investments
where the investor had a stated intention to produce
positive social or environmental benefits in addition to
financial returns. This is consistent with the definitions
ANNEX 1: Definitions of Innovative Financing Mechanisms 27
of impact investing proposed by the Global Impact
Investing Network and the World Economic Forum.
While we made every effort for this database to be com-
plete, it is likely that we did not include all possible innova-
tive financing instruments. We hope to continue refining
this database in the future. If you would like to receive a
copy of the database, please contact us at innovativefi-
Market projections
We projected the innovative financing market size based
on the historic growth rates of different mechanisms. The
higher end of the range was calculated as the maximum
of the historic annual growth rate for all innovative financ-
ing mechanisms between 2003 and 2013 (12.3%) and the
growth rate for the specific type of instrument. The lower
end of the range was estimated as the minimum of the
historic growth rate for innovative financing as a whole and
the specific type of instrument.
In addition, we made decisions based on the availability
of data about which year to use as the baseline and what
period of time to use to calculate historic performance.
Table 2: Overview of Data Used in Report
Number in
Database
Number that
mobilized resources
between 2000-2003
Amount mobilized
between 2000-2013
($ million)
Percentage
of Total
(percent)
Total
mobilized
(USD M)
Securities and Derivatives
Bonds 14 14 23,200 25% 29,500
Guarantees 23 17 36,100 39% 56,700
Impact Investing Funds** 98 82 5,800 6% 5,900
Loans 6 4 1,800 2% 2,300
Microfinance Investment Funds 130 112 9,100 10% 9,300
Other derivative products 13 8 600 1% 600
Subtotal 284 237 76,600 82% 104,300
Results, output, and performance-based mechanisms
Advanced Market Commitments 6 4 1,100 1% 1,100
Awards and prizes 1 10 300 0% 300
Debt-swaps and buy-downs 4 4 1,400 1% 1,400
Development Impact Bonds 5 0 - 0% -
Performance-based contracts 16 13 5,000 5% 5,000
Subtotal 49 31 7,800 8% 7,800
Voluntary contributions
Auctions 2 2 6,500 7% 6,500
Donations a part of consumer purchases 6 4 200 0% 200
Subtotal 8 6 6,700 7% 6,700
Compulsory Charges
Taxes 6 4 2,400 3% 2,400
Subtotal 6 4 2,400 3% 2,400
347 278 93,500 121,200
* Of the 347 mechanisms in the database, only 278 mobilized resources between 2000 and 2013. This reflects the emegence of new asset classes such as
Development Impact Bonds, which did not mobilize any resources during that perid, and new products, such as the DFID Innovation Prizes for Environment and
Development which was launched in 2013 and has not been implemented yet.
** We defined the universe of impact investing and microfinance funds based on the decision of managers to register with ImpactBase, a leading database of
impact investing funds. Many fund managers elect not to register with ImpactBase, which makes this a conservative estimate of the market size.
Source: Innovative Financing Initiative Database; Dalberg analysis.
Innovative Financing for Development: Scalable Business Models that Produce Economic, Social, and Environmental Outcomes28
Definitions of each instrument
Securities and Derivatives
Bonds and Notes
Debt financing raised in capital markets to fund development interventions like microfinance or
climate change interventions
Guarantees
Financial commitment to provide payment in case of financial loss, including insurance
products, that act as a risk-mitigation incentive to attract other funders
Loans
Loans made with concessionary repayment terms to borrowers for implementing specific
development interventions like green credit lines
Microfinance Investment
Funds
Investment funds that finance microcredit lenders in developing countries who provide low-
income and marginalized borrowers with access to finance
Other Investment Funds
Investment vehicles that are structured and funded to target a specific development challenge,
often blending investors with different risk/return profiles
Other Derivative
Products
Financial instrument that derives its value from performance of another asset like securities tied
to residential mortgages or weather events
Results-, output-, and
performance based
mechanisms
Advanced market
commitments
Commitment of funds to guarantee price/market for products once developed
Awards and Prizes
Financial reward for development solutions in a competitive selection process
Development Impact
Bonds
Investors fund development intervention upfront, government/donors repay them with interest
based on results achieved
Performance-based
contracts
Grant contracts structured to disburse based on meeting specific performance targets
Debt-swaps and
buy-downs
Developing country debt repayment obligations are transferred or reduced based on meeting
development goals
Voluntary
contributions
Carbon Auctions
(voluntary market)
Voluntary participation in legally binding exchanges for trading carbon credits and reducing
emissions
Donations as part of
consumer purchases
A percentage of each purchase of a consumer product goes to fund a designated development
challenge
Compulsory
charges
Taxes
Specific tax imposed by government to raise funding for a specific development challenge
ANNEX 1: Definitions of Innovative Financing Mechanisms 29
Table 3: Assumptions used to calculate market projections
Instrument
Historic
Compound Annual
Growth Rate
CAGR implied
by projected
range midpoint
Baseline
Year in
Calculations
Period used to
calculate the
historic growth rate
Projected
Midpoint
(USD M)
Percent
of Total
Compulsory Charges
Taxes and Levies 1.6% 7.7% 2013 2007-2013 687 3%
Results Based Mechanisms
AMC 15.7% 14.1% 2012 2009-2012 985 4%
Awards and prizes -30.7% 3.2% 2012 2005-2012 1 0%
Debt-swaps and buy-downs 19.2% 16.1% 2012 2004-2012 185 1%
Performance-based contracts 21.8% 17.7% 2012 2009-2013 3,321 14%
Securities and Derivatives
Bonds, notes 16.9% 14.7% 2012 2006-2012 5,261 22%
Development Impact Bonds NA 14.1% 2014 NA 110 0%
Guarantees 7.2% 10.0% 2012 2003-2012 9,075 38%
Investment funds 10.0% 11.2% 2012 2006-2012 580 2%
Loans -1.5% 6.9% 2012 2003-2012 18 0%
Microfinance Investment Funds 15.2% 13.8% 2011 2005-2010 2,304 10%
Other derivative products -45.8% 3.0% 2012 2008-2012 6 0%
Voluntary contributions
Auctions -5.3% 5.9% 2012 2008-2012 1,619 7%
Consumer Purchases 7.0% 9.8% 2012 2006-2012 38 0%
Weighted Average 12.3% 12.0% Total 24,191 100%
Innovative Financing for Development: Scalable Business Models that Produce Economic, Social, and Environmental Outcomes30
Ban Ki-moon, L. I. (2009). Innovative Financing for
Development: Leading Innovative Financing for Equity (LIFE).
New York: United Nations.
Banerjee, A. V. (2013). Microcredit Under the Microscope:
What Have We Learned in the Past Two Decades, and What
Do We Need to Know? Massachusetts: Annual Review of
Economics.
Barder, O. (2013) ‘Development impact bonds-BBC world
service interview‘.
Benete L., B. D. (2010). 2+3=8 Innovating in Financing
Education - Report of the writing committee to the task
force on innovative financing for education. Paris: Leading
Group on Innovative Financing for Development.
Benn, J., & Sandor, E. a. (2009). Innovative financing to fund
development: PROGRESS AND PROSPECTS. Paris: The
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development.
Bond, D. L. (2012). Debt Conversion Development Bonds:
Mobilizing Domestic Savings to Fund Development. Paris:
UNESCO.
Bruno, G. a. (2012 ). Rethinking Financial Innovation - Reducing
Negative Outcomes While Retaining The Benefits. Geneva:
World Economic Forum.
Bndes Brazilian Development Bank ‘BNDES Brazilian
Development Bank: concessions and Support to
Infrastructure‘.
Chau, V. e. (2013). The Advance Market Commitment for
Pneumococcal Vaccines: Process and Design Evaluation.
Geneva: Dalberg.
Cole S, B. G. (2012). The effectiveness of index-based micro-
insurance in helping smallholders manage weather-related
risks. London: EPPI-Centre, Social Science Research Unit,
Institute of Education, University of London.
d’Orville, H. (2010). Mobilizing resources for international
development cooperation in education: what innovative
mechanisms and partnerships? Paris: UNESCOs Bureau of
Strategic Planning.
(2009). DEBT SWAPS FOR EDUCATION. Paris: UNESCO.
Development Impact Bonds Working Group (2013)
‘Development impact bond working group paper.
Development Initiatives (2013) ‘Investments to End Poverty’.
Eckrich, R. (2013) ‘Sovereign wealth funds: infrastructure
investment goes international., Handshake 32-33.
Foster; & Briceño-Garmendia (2009) ‘Africa’s infrastructure: A
time for transformation’.
Frandano, P., & Karamchandani, A. a. (2009). Emerging
Markets, Emerging Models: MARKET-BASED SOLUTIONS
TO THE CHALLENGES OF GLOBAL POVERTY. Cambridge:
MONITOR COMPANY GROUP, L.P.
ANNEX 2:
Selected References
ANNEX 2: Bibliography 31
Greenhill, R. a. (2012). The Aid Effectiveness Agenda: The
benefits of going ahead-A commentary on the final re-
port. London: ODI’s European Development Cooperation
Strengthening Programme.
Girishankar, N. (2009) ‘Innovating development finance-from
financing sources to financial solutions, World Bank Policy
Research Working Paper Series.
Hurley, G. (2012). Innovative Financing for Development: A New
Model for Development Finance? New York: United Nations
Development Programme.
International Financial Corporation (2013) ‘Africa PPPs,
Handshake.
Ismed (2013) ‘Mediterranean Guarantees: A newsletter on risk
mitigation instruments for infrastructure investment in the
Mediterranean ‘, Mediterranean Guarantees, 3-5.
Jp Morgan Chase & Co ‘New Investment Fund Will advance
late-Stage Vaccines and other Global Health Technologies’.
Kanbur, R. a. (2013). THE OPERATIONAL DIMENSIONS OF
RESULTS-BASED FINANCING. New York: The World Bank
and Cornell University.
Katz, R., & Karamchandani, A. a. (2012). From Blueprint to Scale:
The Case for Philanthropy in Impact Investing. Cambridge:
Monitor Group.
Kaul, I. a. (2006). THE NEW PUBLIC FINANCE - Responding to
Global Challenges. 2006: Oxford University Press, Inc.
Keating, G. a. (2012). Investing for impact: How social entre-
preneurship is redefining the meaning of return. Zurich:
Credit Suisse and the Schwab Foundation for Social
Entrepreneurship.
Ketkar, S. a. (2009). Innovative Financing for Development.
Washington, DC: The World Bank.
Kharas, H. (2013). INVESTMENTS TO END PROVERTY: Real
money, real choices, real lives. Bristol: Development
Initiatives Ltd.
Lake Turkana Wind Power (2012) Lake Turkana wind power
website.
Lerner, J. a. (2011). The Consequences of Financial Innovation: A
counterfactual research agenda. Cambridge: NBER Working
Paper No. 16780.
Levine, O. S., Cherian, T., Shah, R. & Batson, A. (2011)
‘PneumoADIP: an example of translational research to ac-
celerate pneumococcal vaccination in developing countries,
Journal of Health, Population and Nutrition (JHPN), 22,
268-74.
Lob-Levyt, J. (2009) ‘Part II: Advanced Market Commitments
and GAVI’, In The 1-8 Group Leading Innovative Financing for
Equity (ed) Innovative Financing for Development
Martin, M. (2013). Status of the Social Impact Investing Market:
A Prime. Lausanne: Impact Economy.
Moss, T. J. (2013). Updating US Foreign Assistance Tools and
Development Policy for the Post-Aid World. 2013: Center for
Global Development.
Nick O’Donohoe, C. L.-L. (2010). Impact Investments: An
emerging asset class. New York: JPMorgan Chase & Co., The
Rockefeller Foundation and Global Impact Investing Network,
Inc.
Pay for Sucess (2012) ‘Pay for success: investing in what
works.
Peter Scher the Executive Vice President and Global Head of
Corporate Responsibility at JP Morgan Chase (2013) ‘Can
a new Global Health Investment Fund save more lives?’, In
One (ed).
Rifat Atun, F. M. (2012). Innovative financing for health: what is
truly innovative? London: Lancet.
Sánchez, M. D. (2013). Inter-temporal macroeconomic trade-offs
and payoffs of human development strategies: An economy-
wide modelling analysis. New York: UN-DESA/DPAD.
Savedoff, W. D. (2011). Incentive Proliferation? Making Sense
of a New Wave of Development Programs. Washington DC:
Center for Global Development.
Simon, J. a. (2010 ). More than Money - Impact Investing
for Development. Washington, DC : Center for Global
Development.
Stevens, D. e. (2011). Debt Swaps and Debt Conversion
Development Bonds for Education. Paris: UNESCO.
Tufano, J. L. P. (2011) ‘The consequences of financial innovation:
A counterfactual research agenda’, The National Bureau of
Economic Research.
Weistroffer, C. L. (2012). Microfinance in evolution (An industry
between crisis and advancement). Frankfurt: Deutsche Bank
AG.
Whitley, S., & Darko, E. a. (2013). Impact investing and beyond:
Mapping support to social enterprises in emerging markets.
London: Overseas Development Institute.
World Economic Forum. (2013). From the Margins to the
Mainstream Assessment of the Impact Investment Sector
and Opportunities to Engage Mainstream Investors. Geneva:
World Economic Forum.
World Bank (2013) ‘World Development Report 2014: Managing
risk for development: from crisis fighting to systematic risk
management main messages.
World Bank & GAVI Alliance ‘Factsheet: Advanced Market
Commitment’.